Multiple buyers and sellers are offering homogeneous items in a completely competitive market. No one in the market can affect the market price by his own activities. Because everyone has complete and immediate knowledge of the price at which the transaction is now going place Let's have a look at Pricing in Perfect Competition.
1. A big number of buyers and suppliers
2. Commodities that are homogeneous
3. Unrestricted admission and exit
4. Factors of production mobility
5. The lack of transportation costs
6. Thorough
understanding of the market
A short run is a time in
which companies do not adjust their manufacturing size. During this time, neither
organisations depart nor new organisations enter the business. During this
time, the supply of variable inputs can be increased or decreased. As a result,
the supply curve is elastic in character.
The graph depicts price
determination in the short run.
In
general, businesses must choose the amount of output and price that optimises
their profitability. Profit is maximised under ideal competition under the
following conditions:
i. MR=MC= Price
ii. MC curve must be rising at the point of
equilibrium
Figure-6 (a) depicts the industry's
pricing determination at the intersection of the demand and supply curves at
price OP1 and quantity OQ1. This pricing is set for all companies in the
business. To optimise profit at price OP1, an organisation must modify the output.
The MR of the organisation is depicted in Figure-6 (b) by the MR=AR line. When
the market price is P1, the profit is maximised at point E, where MR= MC.
Let
us introduce the AC curve in Figure-6 to estimate how much profit the firm
makes (b). AR (price) minus AC equals profit. Total profits equal EF in
Figure-6 (b) since AR = ME and AC equals MF. As a result, the profit area
equals P1EFT. These are the organization's above-average profits.
At this level of profit, there is a proclivity for new
companies to enter the market. Organizations, on the other hand, cannot enter
in the short run. At point E, the organisations in the industry will be balanced, but the industry as a whole will not be.
Consider the instance when the price falls from P1 to
P2.
Figure 7 depicts this:
Organizations may be
forced to exit the industry as a result of the losses. However, in the short
run, it is reasonable for firms to continue producing. This is because if firms
continue to generate income, they will be able to pay both fixed and variable
costs.
As a result, completely
competitive organisations prosper in the short run. However, in some cases,
they must experience losses. If the organisation sets a price that is higher
than the market price, it may find it difficult to sell its products in a
competitive market. On the contrary, it must incur losses if it fixes the price
below the market price.
In the short term, organisations may
readily modify variable and fixed components such as labour, machinery, and
capital, however, in the long run, the factors are variable.
Organizations can either increase or
replace permanent equipment. Furthermore, throughout this time period, firms
might simply enter or depart the sector.
The long term AC and MC curves influence pricing and output choices. In the long run, ATC is also a major factor of the equilibrium point. The following two requirements must be met over a lengthy period of time in order to achieve equilibrium.
Price = MC Price = AC
Or, Price = MC = AC
If the price is higher than the AC,
companies will generate above-average profits, which will encourage additional
organisations to enter the field. More groups will increase the supply of the
product, causing the price to decline. This will continue until the price hits
AC and all organisations make just regular profits.
Organizations, on the other hand, would
suffer losses if the price fell below AC. Organizations begin to depart,
resulting in a supply failure. This raises the cost of AC. As a result, the
remaining organisations will begin to make typical earnings.
It should be observed that as AC
decreases, MC increases, and when AC increases, MC decreases.
Thus, MC=AC at the
minimum point of the AC curve, when AC is neither decreasing nor increasing.
As a result, the
equilibrium condition may be recast as follows:
Price = MC = Minimum of AC
Organizations can enter and quit the business in the
long run. When the price is OP1, equilibrium is at point E' in Figure-8.
Profits are made since AR is bigger than AC at this moment. This entices
additional companies to join the business. This will cause the industry's
supply curve to move from S1 to S2. As a result, the price will reduce from OP1
to OP2.
Organizations begin to lose money at this pricing
since AR is cheaper than AC. As a result, the majority of firms will leave the
industry. As a result, the product's supply decreases, boosting the price to
P0. As a result, complete equilibrium is attained at price OP0 and output ON,
where all organisations in the industry make normal profits.
The
market has characteristics of both perfect competition and monopoly in
monopolistic competition. Monopolies are more prevalent than pure competition
or pure monopolies. In this essay, we will look at the monopolistic competition and
its characteristics, price-output determination, and equilibrium circumstances.
1. A
large number of vendors
2. Distinct
product distinction
3. Ease
of entry and exit
4. Non-price
competition
Because
the product is differentiated amongst businesses under monopolistic
competition, each firm does not have a fully elastic demand for its products. In
such a market, each business sets its own pricing for its own items. As a
result, it confronts a demand curve that slopes downward. Overall, we may argue
that the elasticity of demand rises as product differentiation falls.
Figure
1 represents a business confronted with a downward sloping but flat demand
curve. It also features a short-run cost curve that is curved like a U.
1. MC =
MR
2. The MC curve cuts the MR curve from below.
The
MC curve intersects the MR curve at point E, as shown in Fig. 1. At this time,
·
Equilibrium price = OP and
·
Equilibrium output = OQ
Now,
because the unit cost is BQ, we have
·
Per unit super-normal profit (price-cost)
= AB or PC.
·
Total super-normal profit = APCB
The
graph below demonstrates a company's short-run earnings losses.
We can observe from Fig. 2 that the per-unit cost is
larger than the firm's pricing. Therefore,
·
AQ
> OP (or BQ)
·
Loss
per unit = AQ – BQ = AB
·
Total
losses = ACPB
If
businesses in a monopolistic rivalry generate above-average profits in the near
run, new firms will be encouraged to enter the industry. As more businesses
enter, earnings per firm fall as total demand is distributed across a greater
number of enterprises. This will continue until all businesses make only
reasonable earnings. As a result, enterprises in such a market receive just
regular profits in the long run.
As
shown in Fig. 3, the average revenue (AR) curve intersects the average cost
(ATC) curve at point X. This relates to Q1 quantity and P1 pricing. Because
average revenue equals average costs, all super-normal profits are zero at
equilibrium (MC = MR). As a result, all enterprises receive either no
super-normal profits or just normal profits.
It
is vital to highlight that in the long run, a business with surplus capacity is
in an equilibrium situation. In other words, it produces less than its maximum
capability. We can observe from Fig. 3 that the business may boost output while
decreasing average expenses from Q1 to Q2.
It does not, however, since it cuts average income more
than average costs. As a result, we may argue that businesses do not behave
optimally in monopolistic competition. Each business always has an extra
capacity for output.
In the event of a loss in the short run, the businesses
that are losing will depart the market. This will continue until the surviving
enterprises only generate standard profits.
Oligopoly,
according to Stigler Hads, is "that market scenario in which a business bases its
market policy in part on the predicted conduct of a few close rival
companies."
"Oligopoly is an industrial structure defined by a few
businesses generating all or most of the output of some good that may or may
not be distinct," Jackson writes.
Oligopolistic
oligopolies can be homogenous or differentiated. When businesses in an
oligopolistic industry produce standardised goods such as petroleum, aluminium,
and rubber, the industry is said to be operating under oligopolistic
circumstances.
If, on the other hand, the businesses
provide items that are near-equivalents for one another, differentiate
oligopoly is said to dominate. When items are the same, mutual dependency is
stronger; when commodities are diverse, mutual interdependence is lower.
There
is no one hypothesis that adequately explains price and output decisions under
a duopoly.
(i) The number of dominant enterprises in the
market varies. Sometimes only two or three companies control the whole market
(Tight oligopoly). Alternatively, there may be 7 to 10 enterprises that control
80 per cent of the market (loose oligopoly).
(ii) Under oligopoly, items produced may or may
not be standardised.
(iii) Oligopolistic enterprises occasionally
cooperate with one another in the setting of prices and the production of
goods. They like to operate alone at other times.
(iv)
In oligopoly, there are times when entry
barriers are quite high and other times when they are fairly low.
(v) An oligopolistic business cannot forecast
the reaction of other firms if it raises or lowers the pricing and output of
its items. Given the great variety of market settings, a number of models have
been created to describe the behaviour of oligopolistic enterprises.
Causes of Oligopoly:
The following are the primary causes of
oligopoly:
(i) Economies
of scale
(ii) Barriers
to entry
(iii) Merger
(iv) Mutual
interdependence
(i)
Small number of firms
(ii)
Interdependence
(iii)
Realization of profit
(iv)
Strategic game
A monopoly market is one in which there
are a high number of customers and a single producer or seller of a certain
item. There are no near substitutable commodities available in this market. The
new firm's ability to enter the sector is completely restricted.
1. A single vendor and a big number of
customers
2. There are no commodities that are
almost interchangeable.
3. Restriction on the firm's admission
4. The firm sets the price.
A monopolistic corporation is often
governed by profit and sales maximisation goals. Because a monopolist is a
single vendor, it has complete control over pricing and quantity. It must
contend with a downward-sloping demand curve; if it raises the price of its
product, sales fall, and vice versa. It will strive to achieve the level of
output that yields the most profit, i.e. the equilibrium level of output.
1. MC = MR
2. MC must cut MR from below
Ø We
can depict the process of pricing and production determination in a
monopolistic market using the provided graphic.
Ø On
the graph above, the output is measured along the x-axis, while P, C, and R are
measured along the y-axis. Both requirements for the equilibrium are met at point E, hence E is the equilibrium point. We can get the equilibrium output,
OQ, by drawing a straight line from point E to the x-axis. If we draw a
straight line from point E to the AR curve, we will have the AR or equilibrium
price, which is either CQ or OP. The straight line drawn from point E to the AR
curve intersects the AC curve at point B. As a result, the average cost of the
company to generate the product is either BQ or OA.
In
this case, the monopolist's total revenue is OPCQ and his entire expense is
OABQ. As a result, it earns a supernormal profit equal to the area ABCP.
In the short run, a monopolist may achieve
supernormal profit or loss. It is determined by the state of the AR and AC
curves. However, in the long term, a monopolist always makes a supernormal profit.
Pricing strategies
· Price skimming is the
practice of selling a product at a high price, typically around the launch of a
new product when demand is very inelastic. This strategy is utilised to produce
significant earnings within the first few months of a product's debut. A
corporation can repay its investment in the product by doing so. However, by
indulging in price skimming, a corporation risks foregoing significantly larger
unit sales that might be obtained at a lower price point. A corporation that
engages in price skimming must eventually lower its pricing when competitors
join the market and undercut its rates. As a result, price skimming is often a
short-term tactic meant to maximise earnings.
· Price skimming has a tiny market size
since only early adopters are ready to pay the high price. After the product's
early adopters have purchased it, sales volume often decreases since the
remaining potential buyers are unwilling to purchase at the seller's price.
Price skimming can only be extended for a longer period of time if the vendor
has also established a strong brand image for which clients are ready to pay a
higher price.
The following are some of the benefits of employing the
price skimming method:
·
A large profit margin: The entire aim of price skimming is to maximise profit margins.
· Recovery of costs: If a
corporation competes in a market where the product life cycle is short or the
market niche is narrow, price skimming may be the only realistic option for
guaranteeing that the cost of developing items is recovered.
· Profits for dealers: If a product's price is high, the proportion received by distributors
will be high as well, making them pleased to carry the product.
·
High-quality picture: This
technique may be used by a corporation to generate a high-quality image for its
products, but it must produce a high-quality product to back up the image
created by the price.
The following are some of the drawbacks of employing the
price skimming method:
·
Competition: There will be a steady stream of rivals with
lower-priced items challenging the seller's high price point.
·
Gross sales volume: Price skimming limits a company's revenues, which means it can't reduce
expenses by increasing sales volume.
·
Consumer acceptability: If the price remains extremely high for an extended period of time, it
may delay or completely preclude the product's acceptance by the general
market.
·
Disgruntled customers: Early adopters of the product
may be irritated when the corporation eventually reduces the price of the
product, resulting in negative press and a low degree of customer loyalty.
· Inefficiency in cost: Because of the extremely high-profit margins generated by this method, a firm may avoid making the necessary cost cuts to remain competitive when it ultimately reduces its pricing.
Penetration pricing is
the practice of initially pricing one's goods or services at a low level in
order to gain market share. Customers who are price-sensitive are likely to be
attracted by the reduced price. The price may be set so low that the vendor
will not be able to make a profit. The seller, on the other hand, is not
unreasonable.
• Drive competitors out
of the market, allowing the company to eventually raise prices without fear of
price competition from the few remaining competitors; or
• Gain such a large market share that the seller can drive down manufacturing costs due to extremely high production and/or purchasing volumes; or
• Utilize the seller's extra production capacity; the seller's marginal cost of production employing this excess capacity is so cheap that it can afford to maintain the penetration pricing for an extended period of time.
ABC
International wishes to join the blue one-armed widget market. A blue one-armed
widget costs $10.00 right now on the market. ABC has a considerable quantity of
surplus manufacturing capacity, hence the product has an additional cost of
only $6.00. As a result, it chooses to join the market at a penetration price
of $6.25, which it believes it can sustain for the foreseeable future.
Competitors flee the market quickly, and ABC becomes the main vendor of blue one-armed
widgets.
The following are some of the drawbacks of employing the
penetration pricing method:
·
Branding protection: Customers may be unwilling to
convert to a low-cost option if competitors have such strong product or service
branding.
·
Loss of customers: If a
firm just uses penetration pricing without also increasing its product quality
or customer service, it may discover that when it raises its prices, consumers
leave.
·
Perceived worth: When
a corporation significantly lowers its pricing, it generates a sense among
customers that the product or service is no longer as valuable, which may
impede with any subsequent price increases.
• A price war: Competitors may reply with even lower pricing, denying the firm any market share.
Peak pricing is a type of congestion
pricing in which clients pay an extra price at times of high demand. Peak
pricing is most commonly used by utilities, which charge higher rates during
peak demand periods of the year. The goal of peak pricing is to keep demand
within a tolerable range of what can be provided.
· If peak demand is not appropriately
controlled, it will out outnumber supply. In the case of utilities, this might
lead to brownouts. It has the potential to generate traffic congestion on the
roads. Brownouts and traffic jams are costly for all users.
· The alternative is for municipalities to
invest in more infrastructure to satisfy peak demand, which is a manner of
directly charging customers for these negative repercussions. However, this
strategy is typically costly and inefficient since it wastes a significant part
of capacity during non-peak demand.
· Companies will employ a dynamic pricing
strategy to develop flexible charges for their products or services that change
in response to current market demand.
· Businesses can change their prices based
on algorithms that take into account competitor pricing, supply and demand, and
other market variables. Dynamic pricing is commonly employed in a wide range of
businesses, including hospitality, travel, entertainment, retail, electricity,
and public transit. Each industry approaches pricing differently depending on
its demands and the demand for the product.
0 Comments